Li
Keqiang, the country’s recently appointed premier, has vowed to put
urbanisation at the core of his economic and social agenda. Government
departments are drawing up a set of policies, expected to be announced
this year, that are intended to guide more than 100m rural citizens into
cities over the next decade.
The
prospect of a concerted push for urbanisation is viewed with excitement
by everyone from mining companies to property developers and local
officials to stock brokers. As China’s growth slows, they hope the
urbanisation campaign will give the country a boost. They are counting
on it to unleash a fresh wave of investment, create a vast body of
consumers and ultimately propel China past the US as the world’s biggest
economy.
China, which is already highly
urbanized for such a poor country, is determined to urbanize further,
and Beijing plans to move hundreds of millions more people out of the
countryside and into the city.Moving so many people off their farms and into new cities should create a surge in demand for housing and infrastructure, so much so, that urbanization has become the new reason to predict that Chinese growth rtes have already bottomed out and will soon begin to surge again.
With so much future demand for apartments, roads, hospitals, schools, subway systems, and so on, after all, how could China not possibly grow by 7% or 8% a year for many, many more years? Tom Holland has a good, if skeptical,summary of the bull argument in the South China Morning Post.
Any
conversation about China these days rapidly turns into a discussion
about the economic promise of urbanisation. Urbanisation is not just the
centrepiece of new Premier Li Keqiang’s economic policies. According to
enthusiasts, it is the engine that will power China’s future
development, justifying sky-high investment levels, and even propelling a
long-sought switch to a more sustainable consumption-driven growth
model.
Believers
in the potential of urbanisation point out that today only just over
half of China’s population lives in cities. If that proportion were to
rise over the next couple of decades to 75 per cent, in line with the
rich world’s levels, they reckon 300 million people – equivalent to the
entire population of the United States – will have to migrate from the
countryside to the cities.
To
accommodate them, China would have to build a new city the size of
Shanghai every year for the next 20 years. That would entail massive
investment in housing and infrastructure, supporting everything from
commodity to property prices. What’s more, argue the enthusiasts,
because city-dwellers earn more than their country cousins, urbanisation
will boost consumer demand, accelerating China’s economic rebalancing.
Like so many of the earlier bull arguments, however, this new belief
that urbanization is the answer to China’s growth slowdown is based on
at least one fallacy and probably more. The first and obvious reason is
that urbanization is not an act of God, and therefore indifferent to
earthly conditions. Urbanization itself responds to growth. Countries do
not grow because they urbanize, in other words, they urbanize because
they are growing and there are more good, productive jobs in the cities
than in the countryside. In that sense urbanization is not a growth
machine. It is simply a pro-cyclical process that accommodates growth
when growth is rising and reduces it when it falls.And pro-cyclicality is a bad thing, not a good thing. It means that increases in growth are enhanced but reductions in growth are exacerbated, so it adds costly volatility to the economy. As the economy slows, in other words, urbanization itself slows, thus subtracting economic activity. In May I re-read Eric Hobsbawm’s excellent book, The Age of Capital, and remember his pointing out that within three years after the 1873 crisis the number of European immigrants landing on Ellis Island dropped by nearly 70%. Do not expect, in other words, migration to stay high once growth drops.
The second, more important, reason is a little more complex and has to do with the source of urbanization. Let me explain by using an example. Let us assume the state government of Illinois decides to raze Chicago to the ground and build an identical new city a few miles away. Would Illinois and the US become richer?
It depends. If the new Chicago
were exactly the same as the old Chicago, and the workers in the new
Chicago produced just as much as the workers in the old Chicago did
before it was razed to the ground, then Illinois and the US would become
poorer by “re-urbanizing”. There might be the temporary illusion of
wealth created by all the new building, but remember that this new
building would have to be paid for by taxes, and the resulting reduction
in household income over the repayment period would also cause a
reduction in household consumption during that period that reduced jobs
and productive expenditures elsewhere. What is more, if people with
productive jobs left their jobs to build the new Chicago, the true
economic cost of transferring workers from those jobs to building the
new Chicago would be very high.
Urbanization accommodates, it doesn‘t cause, growthBut let us suppose that working and living conditions in the old Chicago were so bad, and unemployment so high, that the creation of the new Chicago required very few productive new workers (most of the workers were previously unemployed and so producing nothing) and caused a surge in productivity at a very low real cost as the facilities in the new Chicago greatly outclassed the facilities in the old Chicago, allowing workers to be many times more productive. If the higher output generated by Chicagoans in the new Chicago were greater than the cost of building the new city, then Illinois and the US would indeed be richer.
This is the key. It is not the act of building all this stuff that creates wealth or real, long-term growth. It is only if building the stuff caused overall productivity to rise by more than the cost of capital and labor employed in building it that a society gets richer.
The same is true of urbanization. Of course if 300 million people move from the Chinese countryside to the cities, we would need to build lots of new apartment buildings (assuming the existing apartment buildings are already full, which is an heroic assumption in China), roads, hospitals, schools, and so on to accommodate them, but these do not make China any richer. They have to be paid for, and their cost is equal to the cost of capital (resources, machines, steel, copper, etc.) plus the total amount of labor that workers building all these things were doing (and no longer can do) before these things were built. We can assume, if we like, that all of the labor was previously unemployed, in which case the labor cost of urbanizing will be zero, but there will still be a tremendous cost of resources.
Paying for these resources would
require transfers from other sectors of the economy, so that the
economic activity created by all this building would be exactly equal to
the economic activity subtracted from the economy. Why? Let’s say that
it costs $1 trillion RMB to house all these urban migrants. This $1
trillion would be paid for by direct or indirect taxes on Chinese
households, which would of course reduce their disposable income.
As their disposable income dropped,
they would spend less on food, shoes, holidays, education, health and
lots of other things, and so the only way China would be “wealthier” is
if the value of the new stuff created was greater than the value of the
stuff that would have been created but no longer can be. If you believe
that migrant workers would prefer to stay home but only move to the
cities because conditions at home are terrible – a plausible assumption –
then it is hard to believe that Chinese households are really happier
by spending more on apartments to house migrants and less on food,
education, clothing, and so on.So does this mean that urbanization must always result in less growth and lower overall wealth for China? Of course not. It can result in greater overall wealth if there are so many jobs in the cities whose productivity levels are so much greater than the productivity levels in the countryside that the increase in overall Chinese productivity is greater than the cost of building all this stuff for 300 million migrant workers.
Once again this is the key. If China is growing so quickly that it desperately needs to move people out of low-productivity jobs in the country and into high productivity jobs in the city, then urbanization is wealth enhancing for China. But urbanization itself does not make China richer. It only allows China to become richer if there is already desperate need for workers in the cities.
So as in the case of razing
Chicago to the ground, urbanization itself will not cause growth. It
will allow growth to happen if the conditions are already there for
rapid growth, and if urbanization allows a transfer of labor from lower
productivity jobs to higher productivity jobs. If China isn’t already
growing quickly, however, forced urbanization will make it poorer, not
richer.
But what if you are Keynesian?
Didn’t Keynes say that simply creating work would make an economy
richer, even if that work consisted of digging holes and filling them up
again? Isn’t it better to build an apartment building than to dig a
hole and fill it up again?No, and Keynes never said that. Keynesian pump priming only works if there is high unemployment caused by the self-reinforcing tendency of lost jobs leading to lower demand leading to more lost jobs as factories fire workers. Spending in itself does not create wealth, and Keynes never said that it would. Spending can create a process that under some conditions can cause the economy to grow faster and under other conditions simply creates an unnecessary expense.
If unemployment in China is extremely high and rising, and if as it rises it causes demand to drop, which causes factories to fire workers, therefore causing unemployment to rise and demand to drop even further in a devastating downward spiral, then building buildings, roads, and services for 300 million new city dwellers is positive for China’s economy. But it is positive only because it prevents the economy from collapsing in on itself.
Notice what this means. “Keynesian” spending on urbanization is not a way to keep GDP growth sustainably above 7%. It is a way, if China’s economy slows so dramatically that unemployment is surging, for Beijing to respond with a massive make-work program to prevent the economy from spiraling out of control.
This why the argument that China is forcefully urbanizing, and that this urbanization will guarantee growth rates above 7-8% for many more years, is almost sheer nonsense. Urbanization is a cost, and if China borrows to fund this cost, its debt will grow enormously. It is only if the resulting increase in productivity on other projects – that is on economic projects that have nothing to do with housing the new migrants – is much greater than the increase in debt that China will get richer, not poorer.
Source
No comments:
Post a Comment