You can always count on Americans to do the right thing, after they’ve tried everything else.- Winston Churchill
When an article appears in Foreign Affairs,
the mouthpiece of the policy-setting Council on Foreign Relations,
recommending that the Federal Reserve do a money drop directly on the
99%, you know the central bank must be down to its last bullet. :
The September/October issue of Foreign Affairs features an article by Mark Blyth and Eric Lonergan titled “Print Less But Transfer More: Why Central Banks Should Give Money Directly To The People.”
It’s the sort of thing normally heard only from money reformers and
Social Credit enthusiasts far from the mainstream. What’s going on?
The Fed, it seems, has finally run out of other ammo. It has to taper its quantitative easing program, which is eating up the Treasuries and mortgage-backed securities needed as collateral for the repo market
that is the engine of the bankers’ shell game. The Fed’s Zero Interest
Rate Policy (ZIRP) has also done serious collateral damage. The banks
that get the money just put it in interest-bearing Federal Reserve
accounts or buy foreign debt or speculate with it; and the profits go
back to the 1%, who park it offshore to avoid taxes. Worse, any increase
in the money supply from increased borrowing increases the overall debt
burden and compounding finance costs, which are already a major
constraint on economic growth.
Meanwhile, the economy
continues to teeter on the edge of deflation. The Fed needs to pump up
the money supply and stimulate demand in some other way. All else having
failed, it is reduced to trying what money reformers have been
advocating for decades — get money into the pockets of the people who
actually spend it on goods and services.
A Helicopter Drop on Main Street
Blyth and Lonergan write:
[L]ow inflation . . . occurs when people and businesses are too hesitant to spend their money, which keeps unemployment high and wage growth low. In the eurozone, inflation has recently dropped perilously close to zero. . . . At best, the current policies are not working; at worst, they will lead to further instability and prolonged stagnation.Governments must do better. Rather than trying to spur private-sector spending through asset purchases or interest-rate changes, central banks, such as the Fed, should hand consumers cash directly. In practice, this policy could take the form of giving central banks the ability to hand their countries’ tax-paying households a certain amount of money. The government could distribute cash equally to all households or, even better, aim for the bottom 80 percent of households in terms of income. Targeting those who earn the least would have two primary benefits. For one thing, lower-income households are more prone to consume, so they would provide a greater boost to spending. For another, the policy would offset rising income inequality. [Emphasis added.]
A money drop directly on
consumers is not a new idea for the Fed. Ben Bernanke recommended it in
his notorious 2002 helicopter speech to the Japanese who were caught in a
similar deflation trap. But the Japanese ignored the advice. According
to Blyth and Lonergan:
Bernanke argued that the Bank of Japan needed to act more aggressively and suggested it consider an unconventional approach: give Japanese households cash directly. Consumers could use the new windfalls to spend their way out of the recession, driving up demand and raising prices.. . . The conservative economist Milton Friedman also saw the appeal of direct money transfers, which he likened to dropping cash out of a helicopter. Japan never tried using them, however, and the country’s economy has never fully recovered. Between 1993 and 2003, Japan’s annual growth rates averaged less than one percent.
Today most of the global
economy is drowning in debt, and central banks have played all their
other cards. Blyth and Lonergan write:
It’s well past time, then, for U.S. policymakers — as well as their counterparts in other developed countries — to consider a version of Friedman’s helicopter drops. In the short term, such cash transfers could jump-start the economy. Over the long term, they could reduce dependence on the banking system for growth and reverse the trend of rising inequality. The transfers wouldn’t cause damaging inflation, and few doubt that they would work. The only real question is why no government has tried them.
The Hyperinflation Bugaboo
The
main reason governments have not tried this approach, say the authors,
is the widespread belief that it will trigger hyperinflation. But will
it? In a Forbes article titled “Money Growth Does Not Cause Inflation!”, John Harvey argues that the rule as taught in economics class is based on some invalid assumptions. The formula is:
MV = Py
When the velocity of money (V)
and the quantity of goods sold (y) are constant, adding money (M) must
drive up prices (P). But, says Harvey, V and y are not constant. The
more money people have to spend (M), the more money that will change
hands (V), and the more goods and services that will get sold (y). Only
when V and y reach their limits – only when demand is saturated and
productivity is at full capacity – will consumer prices be driven up.
And they are nowhere near their limits yet.
The US output gap
– the difference between actual output (y) and potential output – is
currently estimated at about $1 trillion annually. That means the money
supply could be increased by at least $1 trillion without driving up
prices.
As for V, the relevant figure
for the lower 80% (the target population of Blyth and Lonergan) is the
velocity of M1 –– coins, dollar bills, and checkbook money. Fully 76% of
Americans now live paycheck to paycheck. When they get money, they spend it. They don’t trade in the forms of investment called “near money” and “near, near money” that make up the bulk of M2 and M3.
The velocity of M1 in 2012 was 7
(down from a high of 10 in 2007). That means M1 changed hands seven
times during 2012 – from housewife to grocer to farmer, etc. Since each
recipient owes taxes on this money, increasing M1 by one dollar
increases the tax base by seven dollars.
Total tax revenue as a percentage of GDP
in 2012 was 24.3%. Extrapolating from those figures, one dollar spent
seven times over on goods and services could increase tax revenue to the
government by 7 x 24.3% = $1.7. The government could actually get more
back in taxes than it paid out! Even with some leakage in those figures,
the entire dividend paid out by the Fed might be taxed back to the
government, so that the money supply would not increase at all.
Assume a $1 trillion dividend
issued in the form of debit cards that could be used only for goods and
services. A back-of-the-envelope estimate is that if $1 trillion were
shared by all US adults making under $35,000 annually, they could each
get about $600 per month. If the total dividend were $2 trillion, they
could get $1,200 per month. And in either case it could, at least in
theory, all come back in taxes to the government without any net
increase in the money supply.
There are also other ways to
get money back into the Treasury so that there is no net increase in the
money supply. They include closing tax loopholes, taxing the $21 trillion or more hidden in offshore tax havens,
raising tax rates on the rich to levels like those seen in the boom
years after World War II, and setting up a system of public banks that
would return the interest on loans to the government. If bank credit
were made a public utility, nearly $1 trillion could be returned
annually to the Treasury just in bank profits and savings on interest on
the federal debt. Interest collected by U.S. banks in 2011 was $507 billion (down from $725 billion in 2007), and total interest paid on the federal debt was $454 billion.
Thus there are many ways to
return the money issued in a national dividend to the government. The
same money could be spent and collected back year after year, without
creating price inflation or hyperinflating the money supply.
Why It’s the Job of the Fed
Why not just
stimulate employment through the congressional funding of infrastructure
projects, as politicians usually advocate? Blyth and Lonergan write:
The problem with these proposals is that infrastructure spending takes too long to revive an ailing economy. . . . Governments should . . . continue to invest in infrastructure and research, but when facing insufficient demand, they should tackle the spending problem quickly and directly.
Still,
getting money into the pockets of the people sounds more like fiscal
policy (the business of Congress) than monetary policy (the business of
the Fed). But monetary policy means managing the money supply, and that
is the point of a dividend. The antidote to deflation – a shrinking
supply of money – is to add more. The Fed tried adding money to bank
balance sheets through its quantitative easing program, but the result
was simply to drive up the profits of the 1%. The alternative that
hasn’t yet been tried is to bypass the profit-siphoning 1% and get the
money directly to the consumers who create consumer demand.
There is another reason for
handing the job to the Fed. Congress has been eviscerated by a political
system that keeps legislators in open battle, deadlocked in inaction.
The Fed, however, is “independent.” At least, it is independent of
government. It marches to the drum of Wall Street, but it does not need
to ask permission from voters or legislators before it acts. It is
basically a dictatorship. The Fed did not ask permission before it
advanced $85 billion to buy an 80% equity stake in an insurance company
(AIG), or issued over $24 trillion in very-low-interest credit to bail
out the banks, or issued trillions of dollars in those glorified “open
market operations” called quantitative easing. As noted in an opinion
piece in the Atlantic titled “How Dare the Fed Buy AIG”:
It’s probable that they don’t actually have the legal right to do anything like this. Their authority is this: who’s going to stop them? No one wants to take on responsibility for this mess themselves.
There is a third reason for
handing the job to the Fed. It is actually in the interest of the banks –
the Fed’s real constituency – to issue a national dividend to the
laboring masses. Interest and fees cannot be squeezed from people who
are bankrupt. Creditor and debtor are in a symbiotic relationship. Like
parasites and cancers, compound interest grows exponentially, doubling
and doubling again until the host is consumed; and we are now at the end
stage of that cycle. To keep the host alive, the creditors must restock
their food source. Dropping money on Main Street is thus not only the
Fed’s last bullet but is a critical play for keeping the game going.
Source
No comments:
Post a Comment